Category Archives: Politics and Economics

Posts moving to New Site: “Exploring the Problem Space”

From late 2016 on, this blog will only include posts on mindfulness and related subjects.

My new blog  Exploring the Problem Space will also cover mindfulness, as well as  politics, economics, science, and  the environment.  Topic areas  include:

  • Agriculture
  • Basic Income Guarantee/Universal Basic Income
  • Basic Principles and Useful Heuristics
  • Climate Change
  • Governance for a Better Tomorrow
  • Healthcare System
  • Ideology and Politics
  • Mindfulness, Religion, and Ideology
  • Mindfulness, Science, and the Enlightenment
  • Poverty and Inequality
  • Protecting the Environment
  • Psychology
  • The Virtues of Science
  • Trump
  • What are Thoughts?

 

The Perils of Profiling Trump Supporters, Part III

Trump supporters are often portrayed as economically stressed victims of globalization and the decline of US manufacturing, worried about job security and stagnating incomes. But as the last post documented, they do not appear to be plagued by trouble finding work. By and large, Trump Country has low unemployment rates.

Perhaps the issue is finding decent jobs – secure jobs with advancement potential.  Since Trump support varied across states, state rankings of work environments might shed some light on the quality of jobs in areas with the strongest Trump support – that is, where the Trump won the vote.

WalletHub, personal finance website, provided just such a ranking earlier this year, in an analysis of the 50 states and District of Columbia along three key dimensions related to happiness. Sources of data were the  U.S. Census Bureau, Bureau of Labor Statistics, Council for Community and Economic Research, Centers for Disease Control and Prevention, Feeding America, Corporation for National and Community Service, Gallup-Healthways, TripAdvisor, Hedonometer.org, Social Science Research Council, Regents of the University of Minnesota and WalletHub’s own research group. One of the ranked dimensions was Work Environment, which included:

  • Commute Time
  • Income Level (personal earnings adjusted by cost of living
  • Number of Work Hours
  • Current Unemployment Rate
  • Long-Term Unemployment Rate
  • Job Security (measures probability of unemployment)
  • Income-Growth Rate

The top ten states with the best “Work Environments” were Utah, North Dakota, Idaho, Montana, Iowa, South Dakota, Delaware, Nebraska, Minnesota, and Oklahoma. Note that eight of these states went to Trump in the presidential election.

Of course, the WalletHub findings are from just one research study. But these findings are in line with data from other sources. For instance, the Census Bureau’s numbers on inequality show that states that voted for Trump tended to be the least unequal. And in a recent analysis of Gallup survey data for 125,000 American adults, the authors found that Trump supporters “earn relatively high household incomes and are no less likely to be unemployed or exposed to competition through trade or immigration.”

The point in these posts isn’t to create a new profile of the typical Trump supporter but to undermine a simplistic narrative about what make Trump supporters tick.

Next:  the other side of the ledger/evidence of economic distress motivating Trump support.

Reference:

Rothwell, Jonathan T. and Diego-Rosell, Pablo, Explaining Nationalist Political Views: The Case of Donald Trump (November 2, 2016). Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2822059 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2822059

The Perils of Profiling Trump Supporters, Part II

Trump supporters have been portrayed as victims of globalization and the decline of US manufacturing, stuck in low-paid jobs offering little in the way of job security or earning potential.  Angry and desperate, the story goes, they flocked to that champion of the scorned and neglected, Donald J. Trump, who would kick out the corrupt elites, restore  hope, heal  pride, and make America great again.

This narrative rests on the assumption that economic woes go a long way to explaining Trump’s support. Let’s test that assumption.

Compare this map:

2015_Unemployment Rate by US County

…with this map:

2016 Presidential Election Results by County

It looks to me that much of Trump Country – the dark red areas – has been enjoying low unemployment rates in the recent past.  Thus, whatever the economic woes afflicting Trump supporters, trouble finding work doesn’t appear to have been a significant factor in their decision to vote for the man.

Next: job security, work satisfaction, and inequality in Trump Country.

The Perils of Profiling Trump Supporters, Part I

The narrative goes something like this: Trump supporters are a bunch of profoundly unhappy bigots, ill-educated country bumpkins left behind by the forces of globalization, plagued by job insecurity, battered down by inequality, worried sick about their future, consumed by resentment of the liberal elites and racist to the core. Or something like that.

I’m sure there’s some truth to this narrative – but “some’ is one of those elastic words whose meaning stretches from more than nothing to less than a lot.  In other words, vague to the point of meaningless.  More important to me is whether this portrait of Trump supporters is substantially true. Is the evidence is consistent and robust?

First, let’s look at 2016 election map:2016 Presidential Election Results by County

One thing that strikes me is the margin of victory in the counties that went for Trump – at least 20% for the vast majority. In other words, Trump dominated in the counties he won. So if Trump supporters are economically stressed, it’s reasonable to expect unfavorable economic indicators in the areas where they dominate.

Next: Employment, Job Security and Work Satisfaction in Trump Country

Election Map accessed on 11/17/16 from: http://www.economist.com/blogs/graphicdetail/2016/11/daily-chart-7

The Qualities of Good and Bad Research Writing: A Case Study, Part III

In their analysis of survey responses regarding proposed federal policies, Martin Gilens and Benjamin Page compare the policy preferences of “average citizens” versus “economic elites. They use the policy preferences of median-income survey respondents as a proxy for the preferences of the average citizen and the preferences of survey respondents in the top 10% income bracket as a proxy for the very wealthy. They found that if only elites favored a policy proposal, it was adopted by the US government a bit less than a third of the time. But if only average citizens favored a policy proposal, it was almost never adopted. Gilens and Page conclude that “[w]hen a majority of citizens disagrees with economic elites or with organized interests, they generally lose” (576)  – a state of affairs under which  “America’s claims to being a democratic society are seriously threatened.” (577).

So, somehow, the average citizen has become a majority of citizens, which is odd since “average” doesn’t mean “most”. Gilens and Page also seem to assume that if politicians don’t adopt policies favored by most respondents in opinion surveys, they are not truly representing the majority of the electorate. But are survey responses a sufficient gauge of public support for government policy? Doesn’t the public’s behavior in the voting booth matter? After all, politicians need to secure a majority of votes to get elected. If the majority of voters don’t like the policies they get from the politicians they voted for, aren’t these politicians likely to lose their jobs?

Put simply, Gilens and Page are making confident claims about the implications of their research that go way beyond their findings. In doing do, they are violating several basic principles of good research:

“Good research is cautious about drawing conclusions, careful to identify uncertainties and avoids exaggerated claims. It demands multiple types of evidence to reach a conclusion. It does not assume that association (things occur together) proves causation (one thing causes another). Bad research often contains jumps in logic, spurious arguments, and non-sequiturs (‘it does not follow’).” Todd Litman

References:

Gilens, M. and Page, B.I. “Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens” Perspectives on Politics September 2014 | Vol. 12/No. 3, 564-58.

Litman, Todd “Evaluating Research Quality:  Guidelines for Scholarship” 22 February 2012; Victoria Transport Policy Institute.

The Qualities of Good and Bad Research Writing: A Case Study, Part II

In their paper Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens (2012), Martin Gilens and Benjamin Page analyze survey data on public support for proposed federal policies. They found that median-income “average citizens” and affluent citizens (“economic elites”) agreed on policy preferences 78% of the time and when they disagreed, policies supported by the economic elites were later adopted a bit less than a third of the time.  When average citizens supported a policy but the economic elites did not, the policy was almost never adopted. How big this latter data set was, I can’t say:  Gilens and Page do not provide us the figures.

Gilens and Page conclude that average citizens lack influence on government policy. If average citizens get policies they support, it’s only because economic elites also favor the policies. Although they decline to speculate how elites actually exercise influence, Gilens and Page approvingly quote the Communist Manifesto on how the modern capitalist state exists to serve the material interests of the dominant classes.  They further argue that their findings support theoretical models of “Economic-Elite Domination” and “Biased Pluralism”, in which the economic self-interest is central to elite policy support. Bottom line: policy support reflects self-interest and average folks lack influence because the state serves the rich.

Gilens and Page do not discuss potential confounders in their analysis of the data. For example, they identify respondent income as the variable of interest, but income may be a proxy for other factors, like age or education. After all, affluent Americans are more likely to be of prime working age than people at lower income levels and are more likely to be college graduates, as the following chart shows:

Income Quintiles-Selected Characteristics_2012

Given that federal policy makers are usually college educated and in their prime working years, is it possible that the greater political alignment of affluent citizens and policy makers reflects similarities other than income?* Gilens and Page refer obliquely to this possibility but only to ridicule it:

“A possible objection to populistic democracy is that average citizens are inattentive to politics and ignorant about public policy; why should we worry if their poorly informed preferences do not influence policy making? Perhaps economic elites and interest group leaders enjoy greater policy expertise than the average citizen does. Perhaps they know better which policies will benefit everyone, and perhaps they seek the common good, rather than selfish ends, when deciding which policies to support.

But we tend to doubt it. We believe instead that— collectively—ordinary citizens generally know their own values and interests pretty well, and that their expressed policy preferences are worthy of respect.” p.156

Here Gilens and Page are essentially shrugging off serious consideration of confounding variables by using a strawman argument. Instead of addressing whether economic class or factors associated with class impact how much individuals pay attention to and understand policy issues, which in turn may affect policy preferences, they present a cartoonish version of the implications of such consideration: that ordinary citizens are ignorant, their views unworthy of respect, and it’s a good thing elites are calling the shots. Who could possibly agree with that?

Nor do Gilens and Page examine the assumption of a rigid class structure in the US, where average citizens and elite citizens are distinct groups with stable membership. This is simply untrue.  Income varies enormously across the life span, typically peaking in middle age (45-54).  According to Auten, Gee and Turner in “Income Inequality, Mobility, and Turnover at the Top in the US, 1987-2010”, most Americans will spend time in both the bottom and top income quintile. At least 39 % of Americans will reach the top 5 % of earners, 56 % will get to the top 10 % and a whopping 73 % will spend at least a year in the top 20 % of earners. And more people fall out of the top income brackets than stay stuck at the bottom.

So when Gilens and Page say…

 “When a majority of citizens disagrees with economic elites or with organized interests, they generally lose.” (576)

…the majority of which they speak are not the same people from year to year. Who knows? It’s possible that a good number of the surveyed average citizens and economic elites had switched places within the four-year post-survey follow-up period that Gilens and Page allowed for policy adoption.

Next: how did the median-income average citizen morph into a “majority” of citizens and can we really conclude that the majority of US citizens have no independent political power?

 

*As it turns out, income is very much associated with education, civic engagement, and political knowledge.     In “Fault Lines in Our Democracy: Civic Knowledge, Voting Behavior, and Civic Engagement in the United States”, Richard Coley and Andrew Sum found that “the oldest, most highly educated, and highest income” individuals were by far the most engaged and knowledgeable. For instance,  just 7% of college graduates expressed no interest in political affairs. compared to 30% of high school graduates.   Furthermore, as documented by  William Galston in “Civic Education and Political Participation”,  civic knowledge can alter opinions on specific issues, such as immigration policy.

 References:

Auten, G., Gee G. and Turner, N.  “Income Inequality, Mobility, and Turnover at the Top in the US, 1987-2010.” American Economic Review, 2013; 103(3): 168-72.

Coley, R.J. and Sum, A. (2012) Fault Lines in Our Democracy Civic Knowledge, Voting Behavior, and Civic Engagement in the United States. Educational Testing Service.

Galston, W.A. “Civic Education and Political Participation,” Political Science Online, April 2004.

Gilens, M. and Page, B.I. Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens Perspectives on Politics September 2014 | Vol. 12/No. 3, 564-58.

The Qualities of Good and Bad Research Writing: A Case Study, Part I

“Good research is cautious about drawing conclusions, careful to identify uncertainties and avoids exaggerated claims. It demands multiple types of evidence to reach a conclusion. It does not assume that association (things occur together) proves causation (one thing causes another). Bad research often contains jumps in logic, spurious arguments, and non-sequiturs (‘it does not follow’).” Todd Litman

Good research papers are imbued with the spirit of humility. Their authors seriously consider alternative explanations for their research findings and do not overstate the significance of these findings. Based on these two criteria alone, let’s look at Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens by Martin Gilens and Benjamin I. Page, which created quite a stir in 2014 when it was published.

In this paper, the authors looked at pro/con survey responses regarding support for various federal policy proposals and then determined if the proposals were later adopted as US government policy. Survey respondents were classified as either median-income “average citizens” or “economic elites” (top 10% income bracket, serving as a proxy for the very wealthy). The authors’ data analysis revealed that economic elites and average citizens had the same policy opinions about 78% of the time. When both groups supported a policy change, the change was later adopted a bit less than half the time.  When they disagreed, policy changes supported by elites were occasionally adopted but policies supported by average citizens alone were almost never adopted. Thus, according to Gilens and Page, when “a majority of citizens disagrees with economic elites…they generally lose”* (p. 576). They conclude that “majorities of the American public actually have little influence over the policies our government adopts” and “a small number of affluent Americans” have too much influence. (pp. 576-577)

Next up: did the authors seriously address alternative interpretations of their data and are their conclusions warranted by their findings?

* The Gilens and Page paper also looks at the influence of business and mass public interest groups on government policies, which I will not be addressing in these posts.

References:

Martin Gilens and Benjamin I. Page Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens  Perspectives on Politics September 2014 | Vol. 12/No. 3, 564-581 doi:10.1017/S1537592714001595

Todd Litman Evaluating Research Quality:  Guidelines for Scholarship  22 February 2012 Victoria Transport Policy Institute

 

All hail the engineer’s approach to problem solving!

All hail the engineer’s approach to problem solving!

  1. Recognize a need
  2. Define the problem, the objectives and the constraints
  3. Collect information and data
  4. Generate alternative solutions
  5.  Evaluate the consequence of different solutions
  6. Decide
  7. Evaluate the consequences of decisions

I’d add these three principles to complete the recipe:

  1. Whenever possible, insure that decisions are reversible after a sufficient period of observation and analysis.
  2.  At every step, appreciate that one lives in a world of probabilities, not certainties.
  3. At every step, appreciate the limits of one’s knowledge and understanding of the world.

Politicians and civil servants who favor an engineering approach to problem-solving may be dismissed as “mere technocrats”. The assumption here is that either one is the methodical, step-by-step sort, or you are a Big Picture Person – a visionary.  Granted, at any moment, if one is counting trees, one is unlikely to be seeing the forest. But that doesn’t mean an engineer can’t be a visionary. You just have to switch processing modes.

Reference:

James J. Sharp (1991) Methodologies for problem solving: An engineering approach, The Vocational Aspect of Education, 42:114, 147-157, DOI: 10.1080/10408347308003631

The Electoral College – Part II

Care of The Economist, here is how US counties voted in the 1992 and 2012 presidential elections:

Margin of Victory-1992

 

Margin of Victory-2012

We all know who won in 2012. But did you know Obama actually won by the lowest number of counties in modern US history?  Just 712 counties out of 3007  voted blue – that’s less than a quarter of all counties in the US.

These election maps document the emergence of what journalist Bill Bishop calls The Big Sort: the residential segregation of Americans by ideology. Democrats dominate the coasts and big cities; Republicans dominate almost everywhere else.  Within their regional bubbles of the like-minded, Americans have become more confident of their own righteousness and less tolerant of those who think differently.

Let’s return to the issue of Electoral College versus direct election of presidents.  Given the increasingly regional nature of political affiliation, should we abolish the Electoral College? I say no.  If we directly elected presidents, less  populated states would become even more marginalized than they already are, as candidates focused more on vote-rich areas where their party is already dominant.  As a result, no matter which party won, whole  regions would feel disenfranchised and  be steeped in grievance.

Yeah, if we directly elected our presidents, the candidate with the most votes would win. That sounds good.  But if huge swaths of the country are ignored in the process, the center will not hold.  Forces of secession would tear us apart.

Democracy is about much more than one person-one vote. It’s also about accountability to an entire population, not just the party faithful.

The Electoral College Versus Directly Electing the President – Part I

The strongest argument in favor of the Electoral College against direct elections of US presidents is that direct democracies tend toward tyranny (aka “tyranny of the majority”). Direct election of presidents would encourage candidates to ignore sparsely populated regions and focus more on garnering votes in vote-rich areas. Under a directly elected president, residents of suburban and rural communities would likely feel more disenfranchised than they already do in the Electoral College system. Whole states would become politically irrelevant, as the concerns and political inclinations of urban voters would increasingly dominate the national political agenda.

To simplify a bit: the big city would ride roughshod over the countryside.

The Electoral College system mitigates the excesses of majoritarian rule by giving less populated states a bit more influence in election outcomes. The Electoral College system forces candidates and presidents to attempt a transregional appeal because no single region of the country is sufficient to guarantee victory.

Of course, many would argue that the one person-one vote system is still the best. After all, that’s what democracy is all about: power to the people, so the more people, the more power. The majority should be calling the shots.

Next up: a couple electoral maps that illustrate a major problem with this narrative.